Aviation Summer Internship

College students have been emailing me plaintively for months, but I couldn’t decide if I was going to repeat my summer aviation intership for 2009. I have decided that I am going to accept a summer intern and teach him or her how to fly. The internship work will be mostly videography and video editing, so if you know someone who is skilled at communicating with video and wants to learn to fly, please direct him or her to the aviation summer internship 2009 page.

Full post, including comments

Simulating America Circa 2006

In the fall of 2008 as the U.S. government was helping out one company or another, an appropriate term for each government action seemed to be “bailout.” The scale and number of bailouts, however, seems to have grown to the point that I wonder if there isn’t a better way to look at what our government is doing. “Time travel” or “simulation” seems more apt.

Mancur Olson divided the economy of the late 1970s into fixprice and flexprice sectors (more). The U.S. government is dividing the economy into CruelPresent and Circa2006 sectors. If you live in the CruelPresent sector, you lost money on your house, you lost your job or your pay was cut, your retirement funds have been devastated. Thanks to multi-trillion dollar simulation, however, a large sector of the economy lives in Circa2006. People in this sector did not lose money on their house (mortgage rewritten) or mortgage-backed securities (propped up by Feds or guaranteed by AIG (itself propped up by the Feds)). People in the Circa2006 sector still have their job at the same salary, might receive a fat bonus for work done in 2008 (even if employer went insolvent and required government takeover), and have retirement funds that are in great shape, perhaps guaranteed by a municipality.

Who lives in the simulated 2006 world? AIG employees and customers, government employees, health care industry, car makers and parts suppliers, certain homeowners, most of Wall Street. Who lives in the CruelPresent? Retailers, such as Circuit City, contractors and developers, prudent savers and borrowers, renters, factory workers outside of the auto industry, design engineers, graduating college students.

What will it cost to keep half of the U.S. in a simulated world where the housing crash never occurred? It could be much more expensive than we think because the goal has shifted. We started out trying to prop up a few companies for a few months. Now we are committing to maintain a permanent parallel simulated financial universe in which half of America can dwell.

Full post, including comments

Printing Money American Style

Yesterday the Federal Reserve announced that it was going to purchase $1 trillion in long-term Treasury bonds and government-guaranteed mortgage-backed securities (source). The money used to purchase these obligations will be created electronically. How can we understand this?

Consider Zimbabwe. The government there can’t raise enough tax revenue to pay its expenses. The government there can’t borrow from foreigners at attractive rates and certainly can’t borrow in its own currency. How does the government pays its bills, then? Zimbabwe’s government goes to Germany and contracts with a printing company to create some local currency, which it then hands out to government workers and contractors. The result was that the Zimbabwe local currency became worthless (source).

Let’s return to the U.S. Our government can’t raise enough tax revenue to pay its expenses. Despite skepticism from Chinese investors, we can still borrow money in our currency. We take money today from investors and issue them a long-term Treasury bond, a promise to pay them back sometime between 2019 and 2039. Our government uses the money from the bond sale to pay employees, pensions, and contractors. Until yesterday, we were spending our grandchildren’s tax dollars.

The Fed steps in and buys long-term Treasury bonds from whoever is currently holding them. The government has thus effectively purchased its own obligation using newly (electronically) printed money. This new money competes with money that people (a.k.a. “the chumps”) had been saving. The government is indirectly spending money that people were saving in bank accounts, money markets, and other cash equivalents.

How is this different from Zimbabwe? They did their printing in Germany. We do ours inside a computer at the Fed. Zimbabwe paid printing charges. The U.S. government pays Wall Street commissions: an investment bank collects fees when the Treasury bond is sold to a customer and then probably collects some more fees when the same bond is sold back to the Fed.

Full post, including comments

Fire the AIG management

AIG has been in the news again, this time for bleeding taxpayers out of hundreds of millions of dollars to pay employee bonuses for a job well done in 2008. Most egregiously, the very division that bankrupted the company is sucking down $165 million in 2008 bonus. Is there some sort of contract that would require the company to pay these bonuses? The company essentially went bankrupt in the fall of 2008, though the U.S. governnment tried to avoid the actual word “bankruptcy”. When a company goes bankrupt, it doesn’t pay most of its obligations under old contracts and certainly does not pay bonuses to the employees who ran it into the ground (not for moral reasons but simply because it no longer has the cash).

The AIG management has said that they needed to do this in order to retain critical employees. This shows a worrisome lack of basic business knowledge. To give an employee an incentive to stay, you would offer money to be paid in the future, after the accomplishment of some goals or at least remaining at his or her desk for another year. One guy received $6.4 million. For most rational people, that would be an incentive to take some time off and enjoy life, not to keep going into work at America’s objectively stupidest company (they ran up losses far larger than traditional candidates for this title, such as G.M. and Chrysler). The manager of your local McDonald’s is savvier about retention strategy than the AIG executives. McDonald’s doesn’t say “We had a bad year last year and you might be discouraged, so we’re writing you a fat check unconditionally in hopes that you will like us and stick around this year.”

AIG has some complex problems. Figuring out that writing people checks for what they did last year isn’t a “retention incentive” does not require a lot of thought. Would we trust a manager who can’t figure out the simple stuff to figure out the complex stuff? I say “no.” We (the taxpayers) own AIG. We should fire the top 20 managers immediately as an example to the rest. They should be replaced with people who have never been employed by AIG; it would be bad to promote the next tier of AIG employees up to the top because that would effectively be a reward for their demonstrated incompetence in 2008.

Is it risky to replace the top management of a company? We voters do it every 4-8 years for the U.S. government, a vastly more complex operation than AIG.

[Update following a review of the comments: I recognize that these bonuses, from the perspective of early 2008, were for the purposes of “retention”. However, the company essentially went bankrupt in late 2008 and there is no way that a bankruptcy judge would have approved the payouts at 100 cents on the dollar. I guess you could argue that the banks that sucked down billions of dollars from AIG did not suffer the effects of a constructive bankruptcy, so why should the employees. On the other hand, these are the very employees who were responsible for the bankruptcy. Foreign banks got billions of dollars, dwarfing these bonus payments, but they had nothing to do with AIG’s self-inflicted wounds. If we can’t stop Wall Street’s “heads I win; tails you lose” compensation structure, 100 percent of U.S. wealth is going to be transferred to Greenwich, Connecticut, the Hamptons, and the Upper East Side. Why not stop it here and now?]

Full post, including comments

Video model release?

I’ve been enjoying a Canon EOS 5D Mark II for some weeks now, but have not yet figured out what to do with its video capability. Today it hit me… why not use the video to get a model release? Before taking someone’s picture, ask them, on-camera, “Is it okay if I use your image in magazines, advertisements, and Web?” This avoids the awkwardness of asking them to sign a paper model release with a lot of fine print and I would think that legally it might be just as good. The paper document, with its fine print, would have a longer list of acceptable uses, but a person could deny having signed the paper or say that coercion was involved. With video it is easy to see that the environment was friendly, that the subject was free to say yes or no, and that the subject was definitely the person who appeared giving the release on video.

The Statute of Frauds does not list “model release” as one of the things that must be in writing. What’s wrong with video?

Comments from anyone with a law background would be welcome.

Full post, including comments

How Rich Countries Die

This is a book report on The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth, Stagflation, and Social Rigidities, by Mancur Olson. There isn’t a whole lot about how nations pulled themselves out of their medieval stagnation (see A Farewell to Alms for that), so a better title for this still-in-print book from 1982 would be “How Rich Countries Die.”

Table 1.1 shows annual rates of growth in per-capita GDP for each of three decades, the 1950s, 60s, and 70s, in a range of rich countries. Contrary to our perception of the U.S. as a growth dynamo and the Europeans as sclerotic, France and Germany tremendously outperformed the U.S., as did most of the other countries. If we have grown larger it is because our population has expanded much faster than the European countries.

Chapter 2 summarizes Olson’s groundbreaking work on how interest groups work to reduce a society’s efficiency and GDP. Some of this work seems obvious in retrospect and indeed Adam Smith noted that businessmen rarely met without conspiring against the public interest. There are a handful of automobile producers and millions of automobile consumers. It makes sense for an automobile company, acting individually, to lobby Congress for tariffs. The company will reap 20-40 percent of the benefits of the tariff. It doesn’t make sense for an individual consumer, however, to lobby Congress. It will cost him millions of dollars to lobby against Congress and preventing the tariff will save him only a few thousand dollars on his next car purchase. The economy suffers because some resources that would have been put to productive use are instead hanging around Washington and because cars are more expensive than they should be.

Labor unions are a drag on the economy, but a labor union that represents all of the workers in a company will be less of a drag than a union that represents only a small percentage of workers in each of hundreds of companies. The single-company labor union will have some interest in keeping its host company alive by not bleeding it too much. A union that represents only 10 percent of a company’s workers will recognize that it can drive up compensation to double or triple the market-clearing wage without, by itself, killing the host company.

Citizens won’t bother to inform themselves about public policy, especially the details. Given the lack of influence of a single vote, it doesn’t make sense for a non-specialist to invest the time. Olson says this is why we have a progressive income tax, obvious to all voters, and a lot of obscure loopholes that benefit the wealthy and influential. He notes that the benefits of Medicare and Medicaid to the old and the poor are publicized, not the fact that they are “implemented or administered in ways that resulted in large increases in income for prosperous physicians and other providers of medical care” because “the many smaller choices needed to implement these programs are influenced primarily by a minority of organized providers.”

Chapter 3:It takes a long time for special interest groups to form. Olson cites the fact that it was in 1851, a century after the start of the Industrial Revolution, that the first modern trade union formed in Britain. The longer that a society remains stable, the more freighted down with special interest groups it becomes.

The president of the U.S. would like to see greater economic efficiency in the U.S. as a whole. Individual congressmen, however, will push for pork-barrel legislation that benefits their district even if the cost to the overall economy is hundreds of times greater than the benefit (their constituents will pay 1/435th of the cost and receive 100 percent of the benefit). This leads to a perennial conflict between the president and Congress.

Unions or cartels of businesses slow an economy’s response to change because they require the assent of many members in order to effect a change. This makes wages and prices much stickier than in a classical free-market economy. Unions will negotiate agreements that favor senior workers at the expense of junior members and young people just entering the workforce.

Olson would not be surprised by the current auto industry bailout: “Special-interest groups also slow growth by reducing the rate at which resources are reallocated from one activity or industry to another in response to new technologies or conditions. One obvious way in which they do so is lobbying for bail-outs of failing firms, thereby delaying or preventing the shift of resources to areas where they would have a greater productivity.”

Special interest groups create complexity, by getting special rules established for their benefit, and thrive on complexity. If a tax or tariff code were only three pages long, an average citizen would be able to spot the sweetheart deals. If a code runs to 1000 pages, however, nobody will ever understand all of it.

Special interest groups may create government regulation. Prior to the Ford Administration’s mid-1970s push to deregulate railroads, trucking, and airlines, for example, the U.S. government was very effective at ensuring profits and excluding new entrants to the market.

Chapter 4 compares countries in the post-World War II period. Olson says that Germany and Japan did well because their special interest groups were shattered by military defeat. When new labor unions formed in Germany and Japan, they tended to be very broad-based and therefore had an incentive in the overall welfare of their societies.

“Great Britain, the major nation with the longest immunity from dictatorship, invasion, and revolution, has had in this century a lower rate of growth than other large, developed democracies. … Britain has [a] powerful network of special-interest organizations. The number and power of its trade unions need no description. [Olson wrote this book just as Margaret Thatcher was coming to power.] The venerability and power of its professional associations is also striking. … Britain also has a strong farmer’s organization and a great many trade associations.”

“[Britain’s interest groups] are narrow rather than encompassing. For example, in a single factory there are often many different trade unions, each with a monopoly over a different craft or category of workers…”

Olson notes that slow growth can’t be due to something inherent in the British character, because the country was the world’s fastest growing from 1750 until 1850.

Olson cites a study by Murrell testing the hypothesis that Britain’s slow growth was due to special interest groups that took time to form. Murrell looked at new versus old industries in Germany and Britain. The disparity in growth rates was significantly larger in Britain than in Germany.

Britain during the time of the Industrial Revolution had more social mobility and less class consciousness than other European nations. Napoleon and totalitarianism destroyed the Continent’s nobility, reversing the relationship between Britain and the rest of Europe.

Olson preempts the question of “How come the Swiss aren’t poor given that they’ve had stability for so many centuries?” by looking at their constitution, which “makes it extremely difficult to pass new legislation. This makes it difficult for lobbies to get their way and thus greatly limits Switzerland’s losses from special interest legislation.”

Olson asks why the U.S., given its stable government and lack of invasions, hasn’t done very poorly. The first answer is that the U.S. has done poorly, growing slower than France, Germany, and Japan. The second answer is that the U.S. is not uniform. Some parts are relatively recently settled (the West) and/or relatively recently recovered from the Civil War (the South). It turns out that these are precisely the regions of the U.S. that have enjoyed the fastest rates of growth: “the longer a state has been settled and the longer the time it has had to accumulate special interest groups, the slower its rate of growth.”

Chapter 5 looks at medieval guilds and foreign trade. Olson finds that the countries with the lowest tariffs had the highest growth rates. The countries with the fewest restrictions on immigrant labor had the highest rates of growth in per-capita income.

Chapter 6 is titled “Inequality, Discrimination and Development.” Japan’s history is mined for evidence supporting Olson’s theory. The country was stable until the mid-1800s. This led to “tolls, tariffs, regulations, and legal monopolies”; the country was a basketcase economically. The nation was opened up via gunboat diplomacy, which shattered the feudal system and high tariffs. The country grew so quickly that it defeated Russia in 1905 and came close to humiliating the U.S. in 1941.

Olson quotes Nehru explaining that Muslims were able to conquer India because of the “growing rigidity and exclusiveness of the Indian social system as represented chiefly by the caste system.” Olson compares the caste system to the medieval guilds. The barring of marriage outside of one’s caste is explained by the desire of a caste to retain the fruits of its economic exclusivity.

South Africa is next. The mine owners wanted to hire mostly Africans because they could be paid less than whites. The trade unions were controlled by whites and wanted to force the mines to employ at least one white for every 3.5 black workers. Bitter strikes led ultimately to the rise of white supremacist political parties and legislation limiting employment opportunities for blacks. Restrictions on labor were naturally followed by restrictions on social interaction and marriage.

Olson notes that special-interest groups increase inequality in a society. A union prevents companies from hiring black workers at the same wages at whites. A caste system prevents someone from rising above the station to which he was born. Effective lobbying turns welfare or health care programs into cash cows for government workers or health care providers.

Chapter 7 is very timely, being about stagflation and business cycles. Olson points out that no standard economic theories explain how the U.S. and Britain could have suffered high unemployment rates for the full decade of the 1930s. Keynesian economics could not explain the simultaneous high unemployment and high inflation of the 1970s. Olson points out that no economic theory explains why “unemployment is more common among groups of lower skill and productivity, such as teenagers, disadvantaged racial minorities, and so on” (classical economics would have these folks working at the same rate as anyone else, but at lower wages).

Classical economics does not allow for involuntary unemployment. If the labor supply increases or the economy worsens, wages should fall until everyone is working for a wage that clears the market and that enables employers to make a profit despite lower prices for final products. “The main group that can have an interest in preventing the mutually profitable transactions between the involuntarily unemployed and employers is the workers with the same or competitive skills.” In other words, a company would prefer to replace a $60 per hour 50-year-old unskilled white worker with two $15 per hour black teenagers who would get a lot more done, but the old whites will form a union and prevent the company from hiring the young blacks. If the company does need to hire someone it will be stuck paying $60 per hour and it might as well hire someone with an advanced degree and a lot of skills, which explains why the unskilled are disproportionately unemployed.

How could the Great Depression have lasted so long? Olson suggests assuming that a lot of prices are fixed by colluding business cartels and/or by government regulation. The prices are fixed higher than they would be in a free market, which imposes costs on society and guarantees supranormal profits to cartel members. If there is inflation, the losses to the economy from the cartel are ameliorated. The fixed price is no longer than much higher than what would have been the market price. In the event of deflation, however, the fixed price is now ridiculously high, demand for such an overpriced product plummets, and production plummets. Investment in new factories will fall to zero almost immediately.

Olson divides the economy into a fixprice sector and a

Full post, including comments

Decline and Fall of the British Empire

Just finished The Decline and Fall of the British Empire, 1781-1997, by Piers Brendon, an English historian. The book includes some interesting tidbits:

p120: Even in normal years Ireland hovered on the brink of starvation. By 1845 its population had risen to over eight million… [it is less than six million today] A Frenchman exclaimed, “I have seen the Indian in his forests and the negro in his irons, and I believed, in pitying their plight, that I saw the lowest ebb of human misery; but I did not then know the degree of poverty to be found in Ireland.” … By 1851, [end of the potato famine] perhaps a million had died and another 1.5 million had emigrated.

p169: In 1870, the U.S. and British economies were roughly equal in size; by 1914 the U.S. economy was three times larger. The British, however, maintained a leadership position in financial services. They’d lost their lead in manufacturing, but were doing a lot of banking.

p201: Africa was a continent “created to be a burden to Foreign Offices” according to Prime Minister Salisbury.

p319: “Because of the Russian pogroms, Jews all over the world tended to favour the Central Powers. By [supporting the creation of Israel], the Allies hoped to win their support [in World War I].”

p480: The British complained that the U.S. supported Jewish immigration to Palestine because Americans “do not want too many Jews in New York.”

The book is sprawling as was the Empire. One common thread is the incompetence and arbitrary power of colonial governors and staff. England’s best and brightest did not want to go out to India, Malta, Nigeria, or Burma. Civil servants devoted to adultery, alcohol, and accepting bribes, however, were willing to go. Usually the results were disastrous as arbitrary decisions were made with little deliberation or oversight from London, i.e., not too different from the U.S. occupation of Iraq (see my review of Imperial Life in the Emerald City).

Britain held sway over almost every type of people and terrain. Consequently, every type of independence process was tried by England and at least one colony. In some cases, the English nurtured local elites and gradually withdrew. In some cases, the English brutally suppressed local insurgents, torturing detainees and rounding up hundreds of thousands of sympathizers into concentration camps (e.g., Malaya). In others, the English simply packed up and left. With the exception of colonies that were primarily populated by European settlers, e.g., the U.S., Australia, Canada, and New Zealand, the results were similar. There would be violence between religious, ethnic, or political groups, and ultimately some sort of dictator would seize power. We Americans might study these examples as we prepare to shed some of our colonies, notably Iraq. It may not matter what we do or how and when we leave.

Much of the book is devoted to Britain’s most important colony: India. The presentation is a bit different than what you’d get reading a standard history of India as it includes much more about what was happening back in London and how India fit into the overall British imperial scheme. The failure of Gandhi’s attempt to keep India in one piece is covered thoroughly, including the violence started by Muslims anxious to have their own state (modern day Pakistan), but ultimately reciprocated by Hindus to the point that formerly congenial neighbors were killing each other by the thousands.

One take-away from the book is that it probably isn’t profitable to have an empire. It would be better to be a China, Japan, or Brazil than to be the U.S. Industrial competitiveness is more important than whatever temporary domination one can exert over a poorly developed and organized country.

[Note: This would be a good book to read on a Kindle due to its lack of relevant illustrations and maps and preponderance of 25-cent words that many folks will want to look up in the Kindle’s built-in dictionary.]

Full post, including comments

Good simple explanation of the A.I.G. money pit

“A.I.G., Where Taxpayers’ Dollars Go to Die” by Gretchen Morgenson is a good three-page explanation of how taxpayer dollars are disappearing in the A.I.G. bailout. Due to secrecy, she could not follow the money all the way through to the ultimate destination (it might be mostly foreign banks, which would probably truly upset American taxpayers), but the article shows us where at least $50 billion has already gone and where another $100 billion or so is likely to go (hint: none will go into factories that hire American workers; none will go into infrastructure that will make it easier to do business in America; my ideas for economic recovery seem to be receding ever further into the distance).

Full post, including comments